There is a unique tradition of American thinking about
economics that holds a more intense relationship to liberalism than that found
in the context of continental Europe, from which much work in political theory
draws. Michel Foucault’s series of lectures on economics at the College of
France from 1978-1979 acknowledge the distinction between developments in
economics in the European context and American. Foucault sets out to argue that
the role of economic reason is not simply to regulate civil society, but
instead to constitute a regime of knowledge that is ontologically inaccessible
to governmental reason. As he puts it, the market, allowed to function
unencumbered, produces relationships that come to represent truths as dictated
by the logic of the market, coding market judgment as the legitimate expression
of a collective will: “ When you allow the market to function by itself,
according to its nature, according to its natural truth…it permits the
formation of a certain price which will be called, metaphorically, the true
price…the market must be that which reveals something like a truth.” The
revealed truth then implies a corresponding set of appropriate and inappropriate
actions by governments, as “The formation of a natural price…enables us to
falsify and verify governmental practice when, on the basis of these elements,
we examine what government does, the measures it takes, and the rules it
imposes.”[i]
The result
is that prices (and, correspondingly, social locations) are read as expressions
of a market’s judgment. The legitimacy of this market judgment is further
established through Adam Smith’s metaphor of the “invisible hand” which
functions like “the existence of something like providence which would tie
together all the dispersed threads” and for Foucault the key element is the
inability apprehend from where the
hand acts, as “invisibility is not just a fact arising from the imperfect
nature of human intelligence which prevents people from realizing that there is
a hand behind them which arranges or connects everything…It is an invisibility
which means that no economic agent should or can pursue the collective good.”[ii]
For Foucault, even Smith, a figure which some have tried to rehabilitate by
reading against some modern market fundamentalists, implies that the world of
governmental regulation and economic action are incommensurable realms, where the very idea motivation government
(some notion of the common good) renders the government absolutely incapable of
aiding the economy, which realizes its promise only through legitimating the
expressions of pure individual interest.
Crucially,
Foucault recognizes there is a tendency to temporally narrativize the work of
the market. For example one imagines the production of a good, (say, a widget),
that the good is sold (or not sold) at a certain price, and eventually reaches
a point where it has achieved its “natural” or “true” price in the economy,
which reflects the optimal point of its sale for both its producers and
consumers. In practice, however, the process of production and sale is
considerably messier. At the center of liberal economic theory lies a
self-interest human, what Foucault calls homo
economicus, the “person who must be let alone” to pursue “his own
interest.”[iii]
Their own interest is not the same as
the collective interest, but, theoretically, the exercise of self-interest will
end up coincident with the common good or common interest. Foucault implies
that there is more than a little magical thinking in this account, as he says
of their interest that it “is such that is converges spontaneously with the
interests of others.”[iv]
The notion is that the economy works without any kind of outside intervention, with
no external signals or signs as to what the “right” action would, as those
would constitute market distortions.
The result
suggests a kind of crisis for economic theory. Or, at least, it suggests a
theoretical problem that arises if individual choice fails to produce
conditions of public stability. This proposition is what drives work like that
of David Harvey who, in A Brief History
of Neoliberalism, suggests an inability for us to draw a line between what
he calls neoliberalism’s promise to better society “by liberating individual
entrepreneurial freedoms and skills within an institutional framework
characterized by strong private property rights, free markets, and free trade”
and its actually existing products of instability, poverty, and violence. [v] On
Harvey’s view, the “theoretical utopian of neoliberal argument has…primarily
worked as a system of justification and legitimation” for the rollback of state
regulation and the upwards accumulation of wealth for elites.[vi]
Foucault’s
canny mention of the magic of “spontaneous convergence” of interests suggests
how the promise of individual freedom naturalizes political conditions as
expressions of (legitimate) market judgments. Because homo economicus does not and cannot aim at producing a public good,
what he really is an entrepreneur of himself, “being for himself his own
capital” and with that production comes the capacity to consume.[vii]
By engaging in processes of consumerism, homo
economicus “produces his own satisfaction” which suggests that the
classical division between production and consumption as two elements of a
subject has instead been conflated in the proliferation of a more intense
vision of economic liberalism, where labor directly produces satisfaction.[viii]
This analysis is especially
trenchant in the case of America, where the function of the market comes to
encompass much more than in other contexts:
neo-liberalism evidently appears
much more radical or much more complete and exhaustive. American neo-liberalism
still involves, in fact, the generalization of the economic form of the market.
It involves generalizing it throughout the social body and including the whole
of the social system not usually conducted through or sanctioned by monetary
exchanges.[ix]
Where in, say, the European context, the failure of the
market to provide certain goods and services might be more readily read as
expressing a gap between the needs of the nation and the needs of the market,
in American the liberal/individual element in the political grammar can be taken
to imply that the failure to provide for a common good is a result of the
refusal to commit more fully to market orthodoxy. This suggestion works in
concert with the appeal of a regime of liberal individualism itself, which
preys on romantic conceptualizations of heroic individuals agency.
Moreover, the
health of the consumer economy itself has become conflated with the national
interest. Lizbeth Cohen suggests that this conflation was particularly notable
in America following World War Two, when this fantasy of national consumption
was tied to existing political winds:
As Americans lived better and on a
more equal footing with their neighbors, it was expected, the dream of a more
egalitarian America would finally be achieved. Politicians never tired of tying
America’s political and economic superiority over the Soviet Union to its more
democratic distribution of goods.[x]
The capacity to exercise one’s own consumerist agency, to
participate in directing the gestures of the invisible hand, can be taken as an
index of one’s membership of the polity. The importance of these practices
increased as a kind of compensatory mechanism for a decline in the intensity of
attachments to other sources of authority, like religion, family, and social
homogeneity. The market comes to reflect not just the judgments of consumers,
but also reflects the capacity of citizens
to participate in the production of values and reality. The channeling of
imagination of agency to these highly individualized and consumerist visions
also dovetailed nicely with the state-phobia referenced earlier in this
chapter: twixt and tween the recent threat of German fascism and the current
Soviet menace, consumerism was not only an expression of one’s capacity to own
their entrepreneurship of the self, but also a method of suggesting that there
were some mechanisms of expression that could not come under state control.
The health
of the economy, then, does not just reflect a string of numbers on the Dow
Jones, an index of consumer confidence, or the amount by which the gross
domestic product has increased or decreased in a given year. Instead, the
health of the economy corresponds with the imagined health of the American
“people,” whose capacity to act as their own entrepreneurs is taken as a key
marker of their fitness and health as a “people.” A bad economy may not only
reflect poorly on political actors or economic elites, but also suggests an
inability of consumers to properly judge their own self-interest and contribute
appropriately to the economy. The special kind of market fundamentalism that
developed as a response to the fifties consensus about Keynesian spending and
government intervention into the market was itself a populism, one that
constituted itself against the government’s separation from not only the
subject position of actors who existed “within” the market but also with a
basic incommensurability thesis at work about the capacity of the government to
pass judgment on the legitimacy of popular reason. Economic crises do not,
then, only suggest crises for capitalism, but they threaten liberalism by indicting the judgment of individual
actors themselves.
So far work
in rhetoric has competently advanced the study of modern economics, either by
suggesting the intrinsically rhetorical elements of economics as in the case of
Deirdre McCloskey’s The Rhetoric of
Economics and its familial relations to the Project on the Rhetoric of
Inquiry, or in various studies that generate sophisticated understandings of
the relationship between neoliberalism, citizenship, and economic rationality.
Joshua S. Hanan, for example, connects the democratization of economic
rationality to the housing bubble that was partly responsible for the 2008
collapse, suggesting that neoliberalism’s paradoxical relation to its utopian
promises and its actually existing exclusions means that “neoliberalism
materially uproots the very materiality needed to view the economy as a
representation of reason.”[xi]
Catherine Chaput concludes that the most nefarious danger posed by neoliberalism
is its capacity to interpret any situation (and thus exert a perverse
presumptive capacity to frame each situation) by moving “from situation to
situation, disregarding spatial boundaries between the political, economic, and
cultural realms as well as their attendant modes of persuasion, wearing away at
the rhetorical linkages between appropriate discursive choices and agentive
power.”[xii]
Bradford Vivian connects neoliberalism’s capacity to generate intense
relationships to malleable political terms like liberty and freedom to its
actually depoliticizing effects, namely to restrict the scope, character, and subject
of political speech to only safe and apolitical topics.[xiii]
Finally, Megan Foley’s astute examination of the federal mortgage crisis
involving Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac accurately assesses how the “economic” has
come to crowd out the “political” by positioning citizens as the figures who
have the capacity to make market judgments with a government rendered into
incompetent architects of an “infantile
politico-economic apparatus” made helpless in the face of market judgment.[xiv]
Taking for
granted this set of observations about the capacity of the “economic” to both
colonize and confabulate politics, I hope to outline how the conflation of
economic agency and political agency configured the public response to the 2008
financial crisis and the ongoing production of the American “people” both
through the 2008-2010 electoral cycle and the ongoing economic recession. Considering
public discourse both as attempting to perform a triage operation on the
American dream while at the same time disclosing anxieties and fears related to
the state of the economy enables me to suggest that the development of a rather
unique form of individual populism coincident with rather than antagonistic to
market fundamentalism was no accident but instead reveals how America imagines
itself collectively in moments of crisis. Foucault concludes in The Birth of Biopolitics that one of the
key insights of liberalism is the motto that one must “’Live Dangerously’” as
subjects are constantly experiencing their lives, presents, and futures as
dangerous.[xv]
The turn to collective political vocabularies, I hope to show later, can be read as a means
of managing this condition of permanent danger, these anxieties associated with
appearance during times of economic and social crisis.
[x] Lizbeth Cohen, "A Consumers' Republic: The Politics of Mass
Consumption in Postwar America," Journal
of Consumer Research 31, no. 1 (2004): 237.
[xi] Joshua S. Hanan, "Home Is Where the Capital Is: The Culture of Real
Estate in an Era of Control Societies," Communication and Critical/Cultural Studies 7, no. 2 (2010): 194.
[xii] Catherine Chaput, "Rhetorical Circulation in Late Capitalism:
Neoliberalism and the Overdetermination of Affective Energy," Philosophy and Rhetoric 43, no. 1
(2010): 2-3.
[xiii]
Bardford Vivian, "Neoliberal Epideictic: Rhetorical Form and
Commemorative Politics on September 11, 2002," Quarterly Journal of Speech 92, no. 1 (2006): 3-4.
[xiv] Megan Foley, "From Infantile Citizens to Infantile Institutions: The
Metaphoric Transformation of Political Economy in the 2008 Housing Market
Crisis," ibid.98, no. 4 (2012): 387.
ReplyDeleteBREAKING NEWS: USD Currency Collapse
China Causes The USD To Fall?
USD Dollar Drops 50% In Value Overnight?
Hey there
I don’t know you have heard this yet…
But the USD Dollar is on the verge of collapse.
In fact since 1973 it’s been on a downward trend…
Dollar-Index-Past-Forty-Years
USD national debt is at an all time high and now financial experts are saying that China is starting to sell their debt holdings to the secondary market.
This means it won’t be too long until the USD crumbles in value!
>>Watch This Video To Learn More<<
I don’t want to be the bringer of bad news, but this is seriously not good for the US since we already have domestic problems of our own, such as immigration and unemployment.
Our economy can not withstand another hit.
This time the USD might actually collapse.
>>Watch This Video To Learn More<<
Make sure you watch it before it’s taken offline.
Speak soon.
[Mr Mark Fidelman]